The trade impact of the COVID‐19 pandemic (2024)

As a library, NLM provides access to scientific literature. Inclusion in an NLM database does not imply endorsem*nt of, or agreement with, the contents by NLM or the National Institutes of Health.
Learn more: PMC Disclaimer | PMC Copyright Notice

The trade impact of the COVID‐19 pandemic (1)

Link to Publisher's site

World Econ. 2022 May 19 : 10.1111/twec.13279.

doi:10.1111/twec.13279 [Epub ahead of print]

PMCID: PMC9347895

PMID: 35942035

Author information Article notes Copyright and License information PMC Disclaimer

Associated Data

Data Availability Statement

Abstract

Using a gravity‐like approach, we study how COVID‐19 deaths and lockdown policies affected countries’ imports from China during 2020. We find that a country's own COVID‐19 deaths and lockdowns significantly reduced its imports from China, suggesting that the negative demand effects prevailed over the negative supply effects of the pandemic. On the contrary, COVID‐19 deaths in the main trading partners of a country (excluding China) induce more imports from China, partially offsetting countries’ own effects. The net effect of moving from the pre‐pandemic situation to another where the main variables are evaluated at their 2020mean is, on average, a reduction of nearly 10% in imports from China. There is also significant heterogeneity. For example, the negative own effects of the pandemic vanish when we restrict the sample to medical goods and are significantly mitigated for products with a high ‘work‐from‐home’ share or a high contract intensity for products exported under processing trade and for capital goods. We also find that deaths and lockdowns in previous months tend to increase current imports from China, partially offsetting the contemporaneous trade loss, suggesting that trade is not simply ‘destroyed,’ but partially ‘postponed’.

Keywords: China, COVID‐19, lockdown, stringency, trade flows

1. INTRODUCTION

The COVID‐19 pandemic has drastically affected lives and livelihoods and, in the process, has disrupted economic activities throughout the world. In this paper, we consider the effects of the pandemic on China's worldwide exports in 2020. World merchandise trade decreased by 7.4% in 2020 relative to 2019, and this fall has, naturally, been associated with the pandemic.1 In fact, there are several dimensions to the pandemic that are likely to affect international trade: its direct health impact and the associated behavioural changes on affected countries; the consequences of the actions that governments took to prevent the spread of the virus; and third‐country effects due to the impact of the pandemic there. We provide what we believe are the first estimates of how each of these channels affected international trade flows in 2020, viewed through their impacts on the global imports from China.

Our empirical approach is straightforward. We carry out a gravity‐like estimation with measures of a country's own COVID incidence, own lockdown restrictions and the same variables for the country's main trading partners. Our dependent variable is the monthly year‐over‐year growth of imports from China for all destinations to which China exported in 2019 and 2020, at the product (HS 6‐digit) level. We find that the direct effects of COVID incidence (as given by the number of deaths per capita) and the indirect effect of COVID‐induced government measures (as given by an index of the stringency of lockdowns) are clearly negative. According to the point estimates of our baseline specification, relative to the 2019situation with no COVID‐19 deaths, a country with the highest per capita level of COVID‐19 deaths achieved in our sample would experience a reduction of 13 per cent of imports from China. Similarly, moving from no lockdowns to the maximum level of lockdown stringency in the sample would generate a reduction of 17.6 per cent of imports from China.

Perhaps even more surprising is our finding that, although on average lockdowns in third countries do not have a significant effect on a country's imports from China, the direct effect of COVID‐19 in third countries does. Specifically, more deaths in the main trading partners of a country (excluding China) induce that country to import significantly more from China than otherwise it would. Interestingly, the positive effect coming from COVID incidence in the main trading partners more than offsets the own negative COVID incidence effect.

It is important to stress that, although it seems sensible to expect negative trade effects due to the pandemic, in principle, the effect could go in either direction. The reason is that, as first pointed out by Baldwin and Tomiura (2020), the pandemic consists of a joint supply and demand shock. Since both are negative, the resulting impact on a country's import demand—defined as the difference between its domestic demand and domestic supply—is a priori ambiguous. On one hand, the health shock incapacitates some workers and causes preventive reactions by firms and workers, decreasing the domestic supply of goods. Similarly, lockdown measures have a direct negative impact on domestic supply. By itself—that is, for a given level of domestic demand—this tends to increase the demand for imports. On the other hand, demand falls as workers are laid off, and as precautionary motives compel consumers to postpone consumption and firms to suspend investment plans. This decreases domestic demand and therefore also the demand for imports. The net effect is therefore ambiguous. The repercussions of the pandemic in other trading partners of a country on its own demand for imports from one specific country (China, in our case) are similarly ambiguous. If supply‐side restrictions due to the pandemic (e.g. closure of port and airport facilities) make it harder for the country to import from them, its residual demand for imports from China increases. But, if demand falls more than supply in third countries, this ‘excess’ of supply will be met by additional exports to the country, rivalling exports from China.

We seek to resolve these ambiguities, at least partially, by analysing countries’ imports from China, the world's largest exporter of goods. Our results indicate that the negative own demand effect on countries’ imports from China prevails over the negative own supply effect, thus decreasing imports from China. This happens both because of the direct impact of the pandemic and because of lockdown‐induced effects. In turn, the negative supply effect due to the direct impact of the pandemic on a country's trading partners prevails over possible negative demand effects. This reduces a country's imports from third countries and indirectly increases its imports from China.

Naturally, these are average effects, and there are important sources of heterogeneity, across products and countries. We explore several such possibilities. For example, the negative effects of the pandemic all but vanish when we restrict the sample to medical goods, highlighting their idiosyncratic dynamics during the pandemic. The negative effects are also mitigated for products for which a high share of their value can be produced remotely, for goods with a high contract intensity and for those exported under processing trade. On the contrary, the negative results are more pronounced for durable consumption goods.

Interestingly, the results for the average country are driven mainly by non‐OECD countries. By contrast, in OECD members, the impact of lockdown stringency reverses, indicating that domestic demand fell by less than domestic supply there, thus inducing an increase in imports from China. One may associate this heterogeneity with the particularly generous fiscal policies adopted in rich countries to compensate workers and firms affected by the pandemic. However, when we introduce COVID‐related fiscal measures directly in our regression, the results hardly change. We also observe an important path‐dependence: while the trade effect of the pandemic in a country in a month is negative, incidence of the shock in previous months has a positive effect on current trade volumes. This suggests that, over time, contemporaneous negative effects tend to be partially reversed, so that trade is not simply ‘destroyed,’ but is partially ‘postponed’.2

The ‘hub’ from which all imports in our sample come is China. The main reason why we use imports from China is the early availability of its monthly trade data up to December 2020. To the best of our knowledge, this makes our paper the first to evaluate the trade effects of the pandemic for 2020 as a whole. There are two other advantages in concentrating the analysis on worldwide imports from China. First, China has trade relationships with every other economy and is, by some margin, the largest exporter in the world, accounting in 2019 for 13.6% of world's exports, according to the WTO's World Trade Statistics 2020.3 Second, China suffered the most with COVID‐19 in the first quarter of 2020, when the rest of the world was only starting to experience the consequences of the spread of the virus. From the second quarter onwards, the situation reversed and China's economy recovered swiftly. In fact, China's GDP grew by 2.3% and its aggregated exports grew by 4% in 2020, whereas no other major economy experienced positive growth. Thus, in the more relevant period for our estimation, between April and December, the main COVID‐related impediments of trade with China stemmed largely from the situation of the pandemic in China's trading partners. This avoids the difficulties of distinguishing between pandemic‐related factors in exporting and importing countries.

Naturally, the COVID‐19 pandemic has spurred a torrent of research on its various consequences, and trade is not an exception. Some of this research, like Antràs et al. (2020), has developed structural models, sometimes merged with epidemiological models, to study the trade and welfare consequences of the pandemic and their interactions with global trade. Another strand of the literature, in which this paper fits, focuses instead on empirical studies following the approach of standard gravity analyses. While the details of the empirical approach and the specific questions vary, the general goal of this line of research is to explore COVID‐19's impact on trade flows.

Some of these empirical studies focus on China (Che et al., 2020; Friedt and Zhang, 2020; Pei et al., 2021), but their data go only until mid‐2020, thus stopping before the end of the first wave of the pandemic.4 Others use datasets from other countries, like Kenya (Socrates, 2020) and France (Bricongne et al., 2021), or for multiple economies (Bas et al., 2022; Berthou and Stumpner, 2022; Espitia et al., 2022; Hayakwa & Mukunoki, 2021; Kejzar and Velic, 2020). A common finding is that the pandemic has negatively affected international trade flows.

An important distinction between our paper and the existing empirical literature is that we use both COVID‐19 death cases and lockdown policies while most existing papers focus on one or the other. While COVID‐19 deaths are an intuitive proxy for the impact of the pandemic, lockdowns are implemented as a reaction to it, typically when the number of deaths is high or is expected to rise. In other words, lockdown policies are endogenous to COVID incidence. As a result, studying either variable in isolation can lead to biased results, for example with artificially large negative effects associated with COVID‐19 deaths due to the omission of lockdown measures—and vice‐versa. Our analysis is immune to this type of endogeneity because we include both variables as regressors.5

Another key contribution of our paper is to take explicitly into account the influence of the pandemic in the rest of world on bilateral trade flows. The motivation for considering third countries in a gravity estimation context goes back the discussion of multilateral resistance by Anderson and Wincoop (2003), and yet most existing papers have not considered such effects.6 We find that they are quantitatively very important.

Finally, it is worth stressing that our approach can be applied to study other global shocks, when the impacts on a country depend not only on the severity of the shock there, but also on other countries connected through trade and global production networks.7 The COVID‐19 pandemic provides us with an opportunity to assess the transmission of the global health shock and its consequences for trade in goods. Similarly, our analysis could be extended to study other modes of globalisation as well, such as foreign investment and trade in services.

The remainder of the paper is as follows. In Section 2, we provide an analytical discussion of how to interpret the net impact of the pandemic on trade flows. In Section 3, we describe the data and explain our empirical methodology. In Section 4, we discuss the results. Section 5 concludes.

2. PANDEMIC, LOCKDOWNS AND TRADE

We study how worldwide imports from China were affected by the COVID‐19 pandemic. Assessing those effects from the perspective of China is useful because, after the COVID‐19 outbreak in January 2020 and the implementation of strict measures to prevent its spread across the country, China was able to restore ‘almost normal’ economic activities relatively early in the year. Since there may be interaction effects of the pandemic in importing and exporting countries, having a ‘hub’ country where the main effects of the pandemic have been circ*mscribed to the first quarter of 2020 is useful to isolate the effects in the importing countries.

We know that the aggregate level of international trade fell in 2020 because of the pandemic (even if not nearly as much as some analysts predicted initially). It is, however, far less clear how the local effects of the pandemic have affected bilateral trade flows. The reason is that there are potentially opposing forces at work.

Consider first the direct impact of the pandemic on importing countries. If it is higher, then more workers are getting sick (or dying) and isolating themselves socially, while at the same time more firms slow down (or halt) production and investment to prevent contagion among their workers. On the one hand, these effects reduce domestic income and, for that reason, lower the demand for foreign goods.8 On the other hand, they also reduce domestic production; for given total demand, this increases demand for foreign goods. Although it has been common to focus on the former (income) effect, in principle, each force may dominate. Which one actually prevails is an empirical question, and the answer may depend on factors such as the type of product, the wealth of the country and the goods’ position in the global value chain.

Now, as is widely known, governments around the world reacted in different ways to the health crisis, adopting a set of policies aimed at preventing the spread of the virus. In particular, various types of ‘lockdown’ measures have been implemented worldwide. They vary significantly, across countries and over time within countries. The most extreme of those policies is a blanket closure of all non‐essential economic activities in the country. But there are also partial lockdowns and other localised restrictions on economic activities. Although most previous related papers have focused on the direct impact of COVID‐19, it is essential to account for this indirect, but central, impact of the pandemic on importing countries. First, without controlling for that reaction, the estimates of the direct effects of COVID‐19 will be biased. Second, it is useful to disentangle the trade effects of the pandemic between its direct and indirect, policy‐related, effects. By design, the more stringent the lockdown, the more domestic production falls. As a result, both domestic income and domestic supply fall. Hence, just as with COVID‐related measures, lockdown stringency has both a positive effect (because domestic supply falls) and a negative effect (because domestic demand also falls) on the demand for imports. Again, whether the former or the latter dominates is an empirical question and may as well vary across types of products and countries.

Bilateral trade flows are also affected by factors that go beyond the pair of countries in analysis. In particular, as is well known from the gravity literature, bilateral trade flows are affected by policies in third countries. This is especially important in our context, since we study countries’ imports from a single country (China). Surprisingly, this dimension has received very little attention in the literature on trade and COVID‐19—the main exception are the studies of the role of GVCs in spreading the effects of the pandemic, discussed in footnote 7. Specifically, if the main sources of imports of a country are strongly affected by the pandemic and by policies to mitigate its impact, there will be repercussions on the country's demand for imports from other countries (and from China, in particular). To assess that channel, we define COVID‐19 and stringency measures for the trading partners (except China) of a country, as detailed in the next section.

Once again, there are potentially opposing forces operating simultaneously. If the negative supply effects due to the direct and indirect incidence of COVID‐19 are stronger than the corresponding negative demand effects, then export supply in third countries falls. As it becomes harder for a country to import from third countries, imports from China tend to increase to replace them. One may think of this as a ‘trade diversion’ effect: pandemic‐related difficulties to import from some countries inducing a diversion of imports to others (China, in our case). However, the effect may as well go in the other direction, if the negative demand effects dominate the negative supply effects in third countries, leading to an expansion of their export supply. In that case, imports from the third countries will tend to displace imports from China. This third‐country effect can also confound the supply–demand effects of countries’ own COVID‐related deaths or lockdowns discussed earlier. For instance, even if a country's demand‐side effect dominates the supply‐side effect, this does not necessarily mean lower imports from China because imports from other trading partners may be replaced by corresponding imports from China when those other partners are mired in COVID‐19. Therefore, it is crucial to control for the third‐country factors when estimating the effects of COVID‐19 on bilateral trade.

Finally, we expect to observe heterogeneous effects depending on the type of goods, on the level of development of the importing country, on whether value‐added can be produced from home, etc. We discuss these heterogeneity results and other robustness analyses in detail in Section 4.

3. DATA AND EMPIRICAL STRATEGY

3.1. Data

We use China's monthly export data at the HS 8‐digit level over January 2019‐December 2020, obtained from China Customs Statistics. Our dataset covers all of the 242 destination countries or regions that China exported to in 2019 and 2020. Starting in 2020, China Customs report the combined January and February data, rather than for each individually. Thus, we also combine January and February's data of 2019 and consider it as one month. We aggregate our data to month–destination–product (HS6) level and control for China's specific factors over a year with month fixed effects. We carry out the analysis at the HS 6‐digit level, instead of doing it at the 8‐digit level, for two reasons. First, product classifications at higher than 6‐digit levels are not internationally comparable. Second, some variables that we use in our analysis are also defined at the HS 6‐digit level. At this level of aggregation, the number of observations in our analysis is already close to 2million. We describe below our data sources and variable definitions. For easier reference, we also summarise in the Appendix, Table TableA1,A1, the definitions and data sources of all variables used in the paper.

The Oxford COVID‐19 Government Response Tracker (OxCGRT), compiled by Hale et al. (2021), systematically collects publicly available information on many COVID incidences (cumulative cases, death cases and tests) and policy indicators.9 There are nine indicators, which record information on containment and closure policies, such as school and workplace closures and restrictions in internal and international movement.10 Based on these indicators, a stringency index is constructed to measure the strictness of ‘lockdown style’ policies that primarily restrict individuals’ behaviour. The original stringency index ranges from 0 to 100. We rescale it by dividing the original index by 100 to help the interpretation of estimated coefficients in the regressions. The higher the lockdown stringency index (Stringency) is, the more restrictions to individuals and to economic activities the country has.11

Among all COVID‐19 incidence measures collected by OxCGRT, the death‐related measures seem the most reliable and internationally comparable both across countries and within countries over time. Other measures, such as number of tests and number of positive cases, are highly dependent on a country's testing capacity and reporting methods. More importantly, such capacity changed significantly within countries during 2020. Accordingly, we use the measures of new deaths per thousand people as our proxy for COVID‐19 incidence (CovidD). The original COVID‐19 data from OxCGRT are available at daily frequency. The number of new deaths is smoothed over the last seven days to fill gaps when data are missing for a day. We aggregate the data to the monthly level.12

As explained in the previous section, we also consider the pandemic variables of a country's trading partners. Specifically, country i's Stringency_ROW measure is the average stringency of the rest of the world in month t, weighted by country i's import share of product p in 2018 from all countries except China.13 That is,

Stringency_Rowipt=j=1NMijp,2018Stringencyjtj=1NMijp,2018,

(1)

where Mijp,2018 denotes the value of imports of product p by country i from country j in 2018. The import weights make lockdowns in the country's main trading partners more important. We use an analogous procedure to construct CovidD_ROW. Both variables are defined to vary at the HS6‐country–month level. The trade value data of 2018 used as weights are from BACI‐CEPII. Because our regressions cover years 2019 and 2020, using the pre‐determined trade data in 2018 as weights avoid potential endogeneity problems of bilateral trade.

In our heterogeneous analysis, we use several additional variables defined at the product or the country level. We explain below how each of them is defined and their data sources.

Since we study a health shock, we give special attention to medical goods (MG) in our analysis. The list of COVID‐related medical goods is provided by the World Customs Organization (WCO), together with the World Health Organization (WHO). We use its 3.01 Edition.14

As Bems et al. (2013) show in their review, during the ‘trade collapse’ of 2008–2009, the largest group of goods affected were durable consumption goods. Accordingly, we investigate whether a similar conclusion applies to the current situation as well. We define consumer durable and non‐durable goods based on the UN Broad Economic Category (BEC) classification (5th revision).

Also because of the nature of the shock, activities that can be performed from home are affected very differently than those that require physical presence. To make that distinction, we use the work‐from‐home shares from Dingel and Neiman (2020) and Bonadio et al. (2021). Dingel and Neiman (2020) calculate the work‐from‐home share at the occupational level. Based on it, Bonadio et al. (2021) compute the sectoral work‐from‐home intensity measure from the average of Dingel and Neiman (2020)'s, weighted using sectoral level expenditure shares on each occupation. We use the concordance between ISIC Rev.4 and ISIC Rev.3 and the concordance between HS 2017 and ISIC Rev. 3 to calculate the HS6level work‐from‐home intensity following Bonadio et al. (2021).15

Another product‐level feature that may lead to heterogeneous effects of COVID‐19 on trade is the level of contract intensity, which determines how much relationship‐specific capital is required to establish a trading relationship. We use the measure of contract intensity constructed by Nunn (2007), which corresponds to the share of intermediate inputs that require relationship‐specific investment. We convert Nunn (2007)'s original data at the 3‐digit level of ISIC Rev. 2 to the HS 2017 at the 6‐digit level.

The trade modes in which products are exported could also yield different responses from the pandemic, because the level of relationships may vary depending on the trade regime. Our data from China Customs Statistics provide information on trade regimes, mainly processing trade and normal trade.16 Thus, we create the share of processing trade among processing and normal trade at the HS6 product level to investigate whether products exported in that way are affected differently. This share varies at the country–product–month level.

The effects of the pandemic may also vary depending on the position of products along global value chains, because the pandemic is likely to affect firms and families differently. To investigate that possibility, we use the UN BEC 5th Revision data to distinguish goods between capital goods, intermediate goods and final goods for consumption, evaluating them separately.17

In addition to the COVID‐related deaths and the stringency index, we also take advantage of data collected by OxCGRT on worldwide government responses to the pandemic in the form of economic support policies. The economic support index records measures such as income support to those who lose jobs or cannot work, as well as debt relief.18 The original economic support index is at a daily frequency. We take a simple average to calculate the index at the monthly level, which ranges from zero to about 100 in our final dataset. We rescale it to between 0 and 1 by dividing the original index by 100, similar to the rescaling of the stringency index.

Some countries have implemented trade policies in response to the pandemic. We use the measures compiled by the WTO on temporary COVID‐19 related trade policies to investigate whether they affect our estimates.19 Since our analysis is on the pandemic effects on countries’ imports, we only consider import measures, most of which aim to promote imports of selected medical products or materials. For a few cases when a policy applied to all medical goods, we use the WCO‐WHO definition of medical goods discussed earlier. We consider the temporary nature of these policies based on their initiation and revocation dates. The trade policy indicators vary by country–product–month.

Finally, we include the exchange rate in one specification to further control for possible unobserved heterogeneity at the monthly level. We obtain the monthly exchange rate data from the CEIC database. It measures the amount of a currency per USD. A higher exchange rate means a weaker currency relative to the USD.

Table TableA2A2 in the Appendix provides summary statistics for the variables used in our analysis. The data used in our baseline regressions cover a large number of countries/regions (174) and products at the HS6level (4636) over 12months of 2019 and 2020 (January and February combined).20 Naturally, the COVID‐related variables reflect only the information for 2020, since such data did not exist before 2020. The table shows that there is substantial variation in both our dependent and independent variables, including those that we use for the heterogeneity analysis.

Table TableA3A3 in the Appendix shows the pairwise correlations among the four main independent variables. The correlation coefficients among them are all positive, as expected, but are below 0.5 for most of them, except for Stringency and Stringency_ROW, which have a correlation coefficient of 0.6. This indicates that multicollinearity should not be a major concern in our analysis.

3.2. Econometric specification

We estimate how deaths from COVID‐19 and the stringency of lockdowns affect countries’ imports from China using monthly trade data at the HS 6‐digit product level. We consider a country's own COVID‐19 variables and those in its trading partners except China (ROW). A natural empirical specification for such an analysis is the standard log‐linear gravity regression, as follows:

importsipt=β1Stringencyit+β2CovidDit+β3Stringency_ROWipt+β4CovidD_ROWipt+aipy+at+εipt.

(2)

The dependent variable is the log of the volume of imports of product p by country i from China in period t, referring to a specific month between January 2019 and December 2020. The main explanatory variables are the number of COVID‐related deaths per thousand people (CovidD) and a stringency index capturing the overall strictness of a country's policies to control the spread of the virus (Stringency). The ROW measures of Stringency and CovidD are the average stringency and COVID‐related deaths in ROW, weighted by each country's imports of a product from all countries except China in 2018. In some regressions, we also include interaction terms between COVID‐19 variables and other variables. Naturally, all COVID‐related variables are available only for the year 2020; for years before 2020, they are set to zero.

It is clear that COVID deaths and lockdown stringency are endogenous to each other—more deaths tend to induce harsher lockdowns, which in turn tend to reduce deaths. Estimates would therefore be biased if one included just one of them in the analysis. By including both, we capture the independent effect of each variable. It is also possible that other unobservables affect both monthly imports from China and lockdown stringency. However, the nature of those unobservables is not very clear, and perhaps for that that reason the literature on the topic has been silent about it (and about potential instrumental variables).

Instead, to control for other contemporaneous shocks and characteristics, we rely on a large set of fixed effects. We consider a particularly demanding set of fixed effects at the country–product–year level (aipy), which represent any factor that affects imports from China of a particular country–product pair in the same way over the months of a year. These effects capture differences in imports from China due to specific characteristics of the importing country, such as its size, and due to specific characteristics of the product, such as those that make it more or less appealing. They also capture similar effects at the country–product level—for example, factors that make a country have a particular large or small demand for imports from China of a specific product. Furthermore, they are allowed to vary by year.21 In turn, at refers to time (year‐month) fixed effects, which control for monthly level unobserved heterogeneity, including worldwide and Chinese‐specific macro and health factors, as well as seasonal elements. With this wide set of fixed effects, the variation that our coefficients capture comes only from within‐country or within country–product pairs over time.

Instead of estimating (2), we take the year‐over‐year (yoy) difference in trade and COVID‐related variables. This has the practical advantage of eliminating all time‐invariant idiosyncratic country–product effects. Country–product effects that vary at the year level are still present; however, and in the yoy specification, we denote them simply as αip. This gives our baseline specification:

Δimportsipt=β1Stringencyit+β2CovidDit+β3Stringency_ROWipt+β4CovidD_ROWipt+αip+mt+εipt.

(3)

The dependent variable, Δimportsipt, is the log difference between country i's imports of product p from China in month t of 2020 and its imports in the same month of 2019, that is Δimportsipt=100×[log(imports2020)iptlogimports2019)ipt. We multiply it by 100 to help with the visualisation of the estimated coefficients, so it measures the yoy change in trade value in percentage terms. The explanatory variables are exactly the same as in equation (2), since they all take value zero during the whole 2019. Parameter mt corresponds to a month fixed effect. Thus, this chained log difference yoy estimation at the monthly level also removes seasonality and avoids potential issues arising from combining the trade data for January and February. Considering that the trade of a product may be correlated across countries and over time (such as trade in medical goods) or across country–product over time, we cluster the standard errors at the country–product level.22

Compared with the traditional log‐linear gravity regressions, our method has three advantages. First, we can avoid estimating equation (2) with a very large number of fixed effects corresponding to the two sets of country–product fixed effects (one for each year).23 Second, the yoy difference allows an apples‐to‐apples comparison of trade values, instead of comparing them month‐over‐month sequentially, where there may be large seasonal changes, especially since we have to combine January and February trade values. Even with the full sets of fixed effects, the traditional log‐linear gravity regression, based on demeaning the data along various dimensions, cannot fully address the country–product‐specific seasonality (e.g. the sudden drop in trade for most products during Chinese New Year except for holiday‐related goods). Third, with the yoy measure, results are formatted as percentages, making it straightforward to interpret the economic significance of the results.

4. RESULTS

4.1. Baseline results

In Table Table1,1, we consider our baseline specification, assessing the impact of our main variables on the monthly log difference in imports from China, defining goods at the 6‐digit level. In columns 1 and 2, we have only the Stringency and CovidD variables. In the first column, to have an initial picture of how they are correlated with the dependent variable, we add only month dummies. In the second column, we then add country dummies and product fixed effects (absorbed). Naturally, this increases the fit of the regression significantly. In both cases, the two variables display negative and statistically significant effects, indicating that pandemic's negative demand effect prevails over the negative supply effect. The absolute value of the coefficients drops considerably from column 1 to column 2, highlighting the importance of controlling for the additional fixed effects.

TABLE 1

Baseline regressions

(1)(2)(3)(4)
Stringency−22.270***−10.455***−12.629***−19.371***
(1.096)(1.357)(1.431)(1.085)
CovidD−6.362**−5.333**−7.154**−20.861***
(2.763)(2.680)(2.779)(2.567)
Stringency_ROW−0.663−2.925
(2.208)(2.242)
CovidD_ROW20.302***28.589***
(4.365)(4.174)
Month dummiesYesYesYesYes
Country FEsYesYes
HS6 product FEsYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYes
Observations2,032,3892,032,3891,923,3351,923,335
R‐squared0.0040.0340.0340.059

Note

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the corresponding import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. Stringency is a lockdown stringency index, rescaled to between 0 and 1. CovidD measures the number of new COVID‐related deaths per thousand people in the population in each month. The ROW variables are the corresponding COVID‐19measures for the rest of the world, excluding China, Hong Kong, Macau, and the importing country in question. Month dummies and various set of country, HS6 product, or country*HS6 fixed effects are included. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at the HS6 product level in the first three regressions (at country‐HS6level in the last regression). ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

Now, just like in any other gravity estimation, it is important to control for changes in economic conditions in third countries. In our specific case, we are directly interested in understanding how the state of the pandemic in third countries affects trade flows between a country/region and China, as this can clarify the strength of diversion and complementary forces between China and other countries. To do so, we consider in our analysis COVID‐19 incidence and lockdown policies in the rest of the world (excluding China), with greater weights given by those variables in the country's main trading partners, as defined in equation (1). The results from adding those variables to our regression are reported in columns 3 and 4. In column 3, we have the same set of fixed effects as in column 2, to make it clear the sole effect of adding the third‐country variables. In terms of sign, the estimated coefficients on CovidD and on Stringency do not change with the introduction of third‐country variables, remaining negative and estimated very precisely. In column 4, we have instead country–product fixed effects, which we keep in all subsequent specifications. As the results reveal, moving to that stricter specification increases the absolute magnitudes of all estimated coefficients, indicating that some trends at the country–product level mask the effects of the pandemic‐related variables.

We find that lockdown stringency in a country's main trading partner does not have a significant effect on import growth, suggesting that either trade diversion and complementarity effects offset each other or neither is relevant. On the other hand, more COVID‐19 deaths in a country's main trading partners increases that country's imports from China. That effect is statistically significant and large, indicating strong trade diversion when economic conditions in a country's main trade partners are affected by the pandemic.

The three coefficients that are statistically significant are precisely estimated and are economically meaningful. For example, using the estimates from our baseline specification in column 4 of Table Table1,1, we find that moving from a situation of no restriction to economic activities (as in 2019) to the highest level of stringency observed in 2020 (for Honduras in April and May, and for Philippines in April) would yield a reduction in imports of 17.6%.24 For COVID‐19 deaths, going from zero (as in 2019) to the highest level of COVID‐19 deaths per capita excluding micro‐states (0.63 per thousand people in Slovenia in December) would induce a reduction in imports from China of 12%.25 The effect stemming from COVID‐19 incidence in third countries goes in the opposite direction. It implies an increase in imports from China of 16.4% if the country's main trading partners experience an increase in COVID‐19 deaths from 0 to 0.628 per thousand people, the highest value in our sample (for Croatia in December).

In Table TableA4,A4, in the Appendix, we show the individual impact of each of the three statistically significant coefficients following a one standard deviation increase, a move from zero to the sample mean and from zero to sample maximum. In the three thought experiments, the positive effect stemming from COVID‐19 deaths in third countries prevails over the negative effect due to domestic COVID‐19 deaths. However, for non‐extreme values, the negative effect of a country's own lockdown on imports from China is the dominating force. Combining all of them, the net effect when each variable goes from zero to the sample mean is a decrease in imports from China of nearly 10 per cent.

4.2. Heterogeneity

Now, countries differ in how well they can absorb the consequences of the health crisis, and the effects likely differ by type of product as well. We explore various sources of heterogeneity, starting in Table Table2,2, where we look more closely at two types of goods.

TABLE 2

Product‐level heterogeneity – medical goods and durable goods

(1)(2)(3)(4)
w/o MGsOnly MGsw/o durableOnly durables
Stringency−20.520***2.986−17.048***−26.192***
(1.105)(5.367)(1.241)(2.221)
CovidD−22.023***13.275−13.868***−40.231***
(2.622)(12.604)(2.942)(5.260)
Stringency_ROW−2.587−11.6082.995−15.814***
(2.275)(12.729)(2.474)(5.251)
CovidD_ROW25.709***97.187***22.293***39.323***
(4.230)(24.889)(4.676)(9.172)
Month dummiesYesYesYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations1,846,54776,7881,484,363438,972
R‐squared0.0540.1500.0570.068

Note

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the corresponding import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). Month dummies and country‐HS6 fixed effects are included in all regressions. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

The most obvious distinction in our setting is whether the good is helpful in containing the virus during the pandemic. Thus, we split the sample between medical goods (MG) and non‐MG. This group of products includes Personal Protective Equipment products, as well as many other goods, such as ventilators, test kits and syringes. As is well known, demand for some types of MG products skyrocketed at the onset of the pandemic and remains at historically high levels. However, while trade in MG goods is likely to display an idiosyncratic pattern, they correspond to only about 4% of the observations in our sample. Indeed, when we estimate our main specification without MG goods (column 1 of Table Table2),2), we obtain results that are very similar to our baseline regression. Now, if we do the opposite and restrict the sample to MG goods (column 2), we observe that the pattern is indeed very different. Neither lockdowns nor the number of COVID deaths has a significant effect on the imports of MG products from China, indicating that demand and supply effects offset each other. The impact of lockdown stringency in the main trading partners remains statistically not significant. Meanwhile, more COVID‐related deaths in the main trading partners increase imports from China, as it does with other goods, except that the magnitude of the effect is much larger for MG goods. Specifically, imports of MG from China would increase by 5.1% if the ROW experiences an increase in COVID‐19 deaths from zero to 0.051 (the sample mean) per thousand people.

We carry out a similar analysis for durable consumption goods. We are motivated by the previous findings of, for example, Bems et al. (2010) and Eaton et al. (2016), who have showed that the decrease in the demand for durable goods was responsible for a large part of the sharp decline in international trade flows in 2008–2009. Thus, in column 3 of Table Table2,2, we exclude durable goods from the analysis. The results are qualitatively similar to the baseline, but the magnitudes of the coefficients are between 12 and 33 per cent lower in absolute value. Unsurprisingly, then, we observe the opposite pattern when we restrict the analysis to durable goods. All coefficients that are statistically significant in the baseline remain so and maintain the same signs. However, they are between 35 and 92 per cent higher than in the baseline. Furthermore, more stringent lockdowns in the main trading partners cause a statistically significant reduction in imports of durable goods from China. These results show that, despite many differences in the nature of the current crisis and the one after the 2008 financial crisis, both show a particularly strong negative impact on imports of durable consumption goods.

In Table Table3,3, we consider other aspects of product‐level heterogeneity, related to how they are produced and traded. An important element mediating the impact of the pandemic in an economy is whether activities can be performed remotely. In particular, in countries where a large share of the population can work from home, both the direct effect and the government‐mandated indirect effect of the pandemic can be absorbed more smoothly than in countries where most activities require workers to leave home to carry out their jobs. Since both the negative demand and the negative supply effects are mitigated when working from home is feasible, the net result is a priori ambiguous. We assess whether that economic characteristic is quantitatively relevant for a country's imports by interacting a product's work‐from‐home share (wfh_sh) with our main variables of interest.26

TABLE 3

Product‐level heterogeneity—by‐product and trade characteristics

(1)(2)(3)
wfh_shContract IntensityProcessing trade
Stringency−39.826***−34.125***−19.232***
(3.231)(7.280)(1.135)
CovidD−39.882***−89.546***−27.055***
(8.739)(22.425)(2.756)
Stringency_ROW−2.357−2.9383.266
(2.275)(2.268)(2.295)
CovidD_ROW27.232***28.610***25.125***
(4.272)(4.226)(4.289)
Stringency*wfh_sh54.062***
(8.345)
CovidD*wfh_sh50.671**
(22.420)
Stringency*Contract Intensity15.895**
(7.861)
CovidD*Contract Intensity74.297***
(24.323)
processing_sh16.158***
(2.200)
Stringency*prc_sh6.215*
(3.437)
CovidD*prc_sh31.114***
(9.622)
Month dummiesYesYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYes
Observations1,854,1011,885,7971,792,892
R‐squared0.0570.0570.065

Note

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the corresponding import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). Wfh_sh measures work‐from‐home share at product level, based on sectoral level expenditure shares on each occupation. Contract intensity measures the degree to which a contract or relationship‐specific investment is needed for a trading relationship in a sector. Prc_sh measures the share of processing trade among normal and processing trade in China's exports; it varies across destination countries, products, and over time. Month dummies and country‐HS6 fixed effects are included in all regressions. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

Table Table3,3, column 1, shows that the negative coefficients of both lockdown stringency and COVID‐related deaths increase in absolute value but are partially offset by products’ work‐from‐home share. Using the point estimates from column 1, they indicate that the effect of Stringency becomes positive for wfh>0.74, while the effect of CovidD becomes positive for wfh_sh>0.79. In our data, only 0.5% of the HS6 products have a value of wfh_sh above 0.74 (same for the cutoff value 0.79), and the median of our sample has wfh_sh=0.33. Still, the results reveal that having a substantial share of workers that can work from home can significantly dampen the negative impact of the pandemic on imports. Note that the estimated coefficients on the ROW variables hardly change when the interactions with wfh_sh are introduced.

In column 2, we turn to the contractibility of products. Products with high levels of contract intensity tend to be more heterogeneous, depend on long‐term arrangements and on relationship‐specific investments and be match‐specific. This makes it more difficult to switch suppliers, at least in the short run. We assess whether that economic characteristic is quantitatively relevant by interacting contract intensity at the product level with our main variables of interest.27 The estimates for Stringency and for CovidD remain negative but increase in absolute terms relative to the baseline, especially the CovidD estimate. On the contrary, their interactions with contract intensity are positive and significant. This reveals that, for products with high contract intensity, for which it is costly to sever relationships, imports are more resilient to the impact of COVID‐19 deaths and to lockdowns, which have a temporary nature. This result resembles a key finding of Bas et al. (2022). Note that the estimated coefficients on the ROW variables remain virtually unchanged when the interactions with contract intensity are introduced.

Finally, in column 3, we consider potential differences in trade flows that are classified as ‘processing’. The estimates for the effects of our main variables remain very similar to the baseline results. The coefficient of the share of processing trade, which is defined at the country–product–month level, is positive, indicating that this type of trade has become more important compared with ‘normal’ (non‐processing) trade. Furthermore, its interaction with Stringency and CovidD is positive and statistically significant. This shows that, for products crossing borders with a greater share of processing trade, imports are more resistant to the negative impact of COVID‐19 deaths and of lockdowns. This could reflect the fact that processing trade usually involves closer relationships between domestic processing firms in China and their foreign partners.

Product heterogeneity may also depend on the position of a good in the production process. In Table Table4,4, we carry out that investigation by splitting products among consumption, intermediate and capital goods. Of the three categories, intermediate products behave more closely to the average product, which is partly explained by the fact that this group encompasses about half of the original sample. Stringency has a similar negative effect on the imports of each type of good, although higher for consumption and lower for capital goods. The sensitivity to own CovidD is substantially more diverse among the three groups: Imports of consumption goods are heavily affected by CovidD, whereas capital goods are virtually unaffected. This difference may be explained by the temporary nature of the negative income shock, which has a larger effect on family consumption, but little impact on firms’ long‐run investment plans. The effect of lockdowns in the main trading partners on each group of products is even more diverse. It is mute for intermediate products (like for the average product), negative and significant for consumption goods and positive and significant for capital goods. This suggests that, if it is difficult to import capital goods from the main trading partners due to lockdown policies there, firms turn to China to keep their investment plans.

TABLE 4

Product‐level heterogeneity—by position in value chains

(1)(2)(3)
ConsumptionIntermediateCapital
Stringency−25.480***−17.296***−15.731***
(2.467)(1.581)(2.479)
CovidD−41.149***−16.130***1.858
(5.669)(3.844)(5.647)
Stringency_ROW−16.336***−0.76020.107***
(5.521)(2.961)(5.467)
CovidD_ROW31.678***20.677***22.257**
(9.635)(5.796)(10.198)
Month dummiesYesYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYes
Observations394,896936,281352,491
R‐squared0.0770.0560.045

Notes

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the corresponding import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). The three regressions use the subsamples of final goods for consumption, intermediate goods, and capital goods based the UN BEC classification. Month dummies and country‐HS6 fixed effects are included in all regressions. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

Now, the level of development, and of the wealth, of a country is also likely to be an important mediator of how a country reacts to the pandemic. For example, we have seen that, on average, both CovidD and Stringency have a strong negative effect on countries’ imports from China. This is likely caused by the negative income effect of the pandemic, which tends to lower consumption, especially in nations where individuals are more credit constrained and have lower savings/wealth that could be used to smooth consumption. In contrast, in rich countries, the temporary loss of income, which is likely to have a small effect on lifetime income, may have a smaller impact due to better access to credit and to personal savings. To verify that possibility, in Table Table5,5, we split the sample between OECD countries (column 1) and non‐OECD countries (column 2). The sample without OECD countries yields results that are qualitatively similar to the baseline results in Table Table1.1. This is to be expected, since they comprise 69 per cent of the sample. In contrast, column 1 reveals that rich countries have reacted very differently to lockdowns with respect to their imports from China. Specifically, the effect of stricter lockdowns is positive for them, indicating that the negative demand effect is dwarfed by the negative supply effect, which induces local consumers and firms to turn to China to replace domestic goods when these cannot be produced locally due to restrictions on economic activities. The other coefficients are, however, relatively similar to those in the group of non‐OECD countries.

TABLE 5

Country‐level heterogeneity—level of development

(1)(2)(3)(4)
OECDw/o OECDEcon supportw/o USA
Stringency6.401***−22.721***−23.563***−19.587***
(2.258)(1.266)(1.153)(1.088)
CovidD−40.218***−38.937***−18.821***−20.073***
(3.724)(4.053)(2.586)(2.606)
Stringency_ROW−5.1481.270−2.112−3.341
(5.123)(2.537)(2.241)(2.263)
CovidD_ROW14.841*18.168***27.717***28.042***
(7.756)(5.007)(4.182)(4.227)
Economic Support1.261*
(0.695)
Month dummiesYesYesYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYesYes
Observations613,3181,310,0171,904,8971,886,201
R‐squared0.1110.0580.0600.058

Note

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the corresponding import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). The first regressions use the subsample of OECD countries that became members before 2010. The second regression covers all other countries except the OCED members. In the third regression, we add an additional variable ‐‐ economic support, which is an index for income supports and debt relief. The last regression drops the observations related to the imports from China by the USA. Month dummies and country‐HS6 fixed effects are included in all regressions. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

One possible reason for the differential effects of a country's own lockdown on its imports for developed and developing economies may be their fiscal redistributive policies during the pandemic. Generally, they have been significantly more generous in rich countries than in poor ones, not only in absolute terms but also as a percentage of GDP.28 We consider that explicitly in column 3, where we introduce a measure of the value of a country's economic support to the population due to the pandemic. The coefficient on that variable is positive, as expected, and is statistically significant at the 10% level. Nevertheless, the estimates of the four main variables are hardly affected by the inclusion of that variable in the regression, indicating that the pandemic‐motivated fiscal policies increased demand for imports, but did so in a way that was largely unrelated to the specific effects of the pandemic on imports from China.

In column 4 of Table Table5,5, we do something different: eliminate the United States from the regression. A concern is that, because of the ongoing trade war between the United States and China, and because the United States is the largest importer of China, there could be confounding effects due to the extra tariffs on Chinese exports. We do not expect the trade war to play a central role in our estimations, since it took off in 2018 and between 2019 and 2020 there were relatively few policy changes (despite an ambitious but unenforced bilateral agreement to manage bilateral trade flows). The results in column 4 confirm our prior: The estimates are remarkably similar to those in the baseline estimation, indicating that including or not the United States in the estimations makes little difference, and therefore, the United States–China trade war is not a driver of our results.

4.3. Path‐dependence, extensive margin and robustness

In Table Table6,6, we consider five additional issues: path‐dependence, pandemic‐related trade policies, time‐varying sector level heterogeneity, control for exchange rates and the extensive margin of trade. Both the Stringency and the CovidD variables are serially autocorrelated. Thus, it is plausible that the trade effects of the pandemic in a month may be affected by the level of those variables in previous periods. In column 1 of Table Table6,6, we evaluate that possibility, adding the two variables measuring the cumulative sum of Stringency and COVID‐related deaths in the previous months of 2020. The results show that the estimates for the own variables remain similar to the baseline after the introduction of their previous values, as do the estimates for the ROW variables, with relatively small changes in the magnitudes of the estimated coefficients. In contrast, both previous Stringency and previous CovidD have a positive and statistically significant sign. This indicates that the pandemic introduces a component of intertemporal substitution in countries’ imports. A nation that restricts its imports in a month when it is badly hit will at least partially compensate for that reduction in the future. We note further that, relative to their contemporaneous effects, the magnitude of this intertemporal compensatory effect is greater for CovidD than for Stringency effects.29

TABLE 6

Path‐dependence, trade policies, HS2*Month fixed effects, Exchange Rate, and the extensive margin

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Path‐dependenceTrade policiesHS2*Month FEsExch. RateExtensive Margin
Stringency−26.541***−19.153***−18.685***−22.978***−0.034
(1.224)(1.088)(1.086)(1.263)(0.043)
CovidD−20.262***−20.292***−20.865***−12.276***−0.196*
(2.638)(2.573)(2.556)(2.662)(0.108)
Stringency_ROW−3.306−2.9301.209−6.018**0.049
(2.242)(2.249)(2.258)(2.529)(0.161)
CovidD_ROW31.224***28.047***20.193***26.220***−0.052
(4.176)(4.193)(4.217)(4.7447)(0.287)
Stringency_prev2.444***
(0.003)
CovidD_prev4.019***
(1.060)
Exchange Rate−2.28e−06***
(1.24e−08)
Month dummiesYesYesYesYesYes
Country FEsYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYesYes
HS2‐Month FEsYes
Observations1,923,3351,903,7111,923,3351,598,8961,772
R‐squared0.0590.0580.0620.0670.385

Notes

See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). The first four regressions are similar to the last regression in Table Table11 except that (1) in the first regression, we add two additional variables: Stringency_prev and CovidD_prev, which are the cumulative sums of their values in the previous months of 2020; (2) in the second regression, we drop observations when the COVID‐related temporary import liberalisation or restriction measures apply; (3) in the third regression, we add HS2‐Month dummies as additional covariates; (4) in the fourth regression, we add exchange rate as an additional explanatory variable. In the last regression, the dependent variable is the log difference between the total number of HS6level product lines with positive import values in 2020 and that in 2019. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level in the first three regressions while at country level in the last regression, respectively. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

A few countries have implemented temporary trade policies in 2020 to cope with COVID‐19. Most of these measures sought to promote imports or restrict exports of medical goods or materials to meet the increasing domestic demand, with a few cases of import restriction measures. Omitting these policies may lead to biased estimates. Since we study countries’ imports, we consider only the import measures, as reported by the WTO. Specifically, in column 2 of Table Table6,6, we drop the observations affected by these policies (about 1% of the sample). The estimated coefficients are very similar to what we obtain from the baseline regression.30

Recall that our empirical strategy, based on yoy changes and country–product fixed effects, eliminates country–product‐specific heterogeneity that is either fixed over time or varies annually. Now, there may also exist product‐specific short‐term shocks at the monthly level. To control for that, in column 3 of Table Table6,6, we add HS2‐month fixed effects along with the HS6‐country fixed effects. The signs and significance of the coefficients are the same as in our baseline regression. Except for the estimate for the effect of CovidD_ROW, which falls by about 30%, the magnitudes of the estimated coefficients hardly change either, indicating that those shocks are not central for our estimation.

There is also a concern about potential omitted variable bias in our regressions. To address this issue, in addition to the large set of fixed effects described above, we also consider cross‐country factors. Although most of the available data are reported at an annual frequency, one important trade‐related variable that is available for most countries in 2020 at a higher frequency is the exchange rate. We define it as the amount of a currency per USD. Since the Chinese Yuan is closely linked to the USD through a basket of key currencies, a higher exchage rate implies a stronger Yuan, which is likely to hurt imports from China. Given the multiple ways COVID affects the economy, the exchange rate may be related to the country's COVID variables, although it is not clear ex‐ante what the main channels would be. In column 4 of Table Table6,6, we report the results from adding the exchange rate variable to the benchmark specification. The coefficient of the exchange rate variable is negative and highly significant, as expected. However, its magnitude is very small. More importantly, the coefficients of the main variables bear the same signs and similar magnitudes as in our benchmark specification, except that the coefficient of Stringency in ROW is now statistically significant. Note that this regression is not directly comparable to the benchmark, because they use different samples: nearly a third of million observations are dropped due to missing monthly exchange rate data.

Now, since our dependent variable is the log difference in imports from China at the country–product level, we are effectively carrying out the analysis at the intensive margin; any country–product pair not observed in a month does not contribute to the estimations. We can also look at the extensive margin. A simple way to do that is to consider how the number of products imported from China by a country has changed from a given month in 2019 to the same month in 2020. More precisely, we compare the change in the number of HS6 product lines at the country–month level between the two years, so the dependent variable is also a yoy measure at the country–month level. The results are in column 5 of Table Table6.6. Interestingly, the effects are almost all mute.31 Although the sample is substantially smaller in this case, it still has almost 1800 observations. The absence of effects suggests that the impacts are mostly at the intensive rather than at the extensive margin. This is consistent with the findings about the nature of the great trade collapse following the financial crisis of 2008, which was also largely driven by the intensive margin of trade (Bems et al., 2013).

Finally, in Table Table7,7, we evaluate whether our results may be driven by outliers. The histogram of our dependent variable (Figure (FigureA1)A1) shows that its distribution is fairly ‘well‐behaved,’ indicating the presence of few outliers. However, Table TableA1A1 shows that the maximum and minimum of the distribution are indeed very large in absolute values. To check whether they are key to our findings, we run three different specifications. In column 1, we drop all observations where the absolute value of the dependent variable is above 500 per cent. This amounts to dropping approximately 2.6% of the observations. In column 2, we drop all the observations for micro‐states, defined as countries with population smaller than a half million in 2018. They correspond to 18 of the 174 countries in the baseline regression. Since those tiny countries may behave differently and be responsible for outliers both in the dependent variable and in some of the key independent variables—as in the case of San Marino, which has the highest value for CovidD in the sample—we want to investigate whether they are disproportionately affecting the results. Finally, in column 3, we run a median regression instead of an OLS. The results in column 1 are very similar to our baseline. The results in column 2 are almost identical to the baseline, showing that micro‐states are largely irrelevant for the estimates. Similarly, the median regression also shows results that are strikingly similar to our baseline, indicating that the latter is not highly affected by outliers.

TABLE 7

Outliers

(1)(2)(3)
Abs(depvar)<5Drop micro‐statesMedian regression
Stringency−15.794***−19.420***−19.557***
(0.912)(1.093)(1.571)
CovidD−21.165***−20.608***−21.302***
(2.079)(2.568)(3.820)
Stringency_ROW−2.715−2.912−2.410
(1.850)(2.250)(3.090)
CovidD_ROW21.304***28.696***28.583***
(3.451)(4.190)(6.541)
Month dummiesYesYesYes
Country‐HS6 FEsYesYesYes
Observations1,873,3581,900,7261,923,335
R‐squared0.0580.060

Notes

Dependent variable is year‐over‐year (yoy) log difference between a country i's imports of product (p) from China in month t of 2020 and the import value in the same month of 2019, multiplied by 100, that is Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt. See the footnote of Table Table11 for definitions of COVID‐related variables (Stringency, CovidD and ROW variables). The first regression drops the outliers defined as abs (Δimport)>500. The second one drops micro‐states, defined as countries with population in 2018less than a half million. The last regression is a median regression. Month dummies and country‐HS6 fixed effects are included in all regressions. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at country‐HS6level in the first two regressions. ***p<.01, **p<.05, *p<.1.

5. CONCLUSION

When fighting pandemics, governments need to weigh the benefits from containing the spread of the virus against the cost of foregone economic activities, of which trade is an important component. As the COVID‐19 pandemic demonstrated, predicting the health and the economic impact of the disease, as well as the consequences of governments’ reactions to it, is a daunting task, in part because there are not many precedents. Here, we provide the first estimates of how this pandemic has affected international trade flows considering the whole year of 2020. Estimates like these are critical for the design of optimal policies to deal with future pandemics. For example, several structural models have been developed since the onset of the COVID‐19 crisis. Our results can be useful in that effort by providing credible benchmark estimates of the direct effect of the pandemic and of the policies to prevent its spread on trade flows. These estimates could potentially be translated into elasticities for the calibration of those models.

Furthermore, our results highlight how bilateral trade flows are affected by the state of the pandemic in other countries, suggesting that any structural model should incorporate that third‐country channel. In fact, these third‐country effects make clear that optimal policies to deal with a pandemic ought to be coordinated across countries. While this is intuitive, policymakers require credible estimates for the size and nature of these interdependencies. We provide such estimates for trade flows at the country–product level, using data on exports from China to every country and region in the world. This allows us to isolate the effects of the pandemic on importing countries.

Because COVID‐19 represents both a demand and a supply shock, its effect on a country's demand for imports is a priori ambiguous. Here, we show the net effects, as can be inferred from country's imports from China. Moreover, we distinguish between the direct effects of the pandemic captured by COVID‐19 deaths on the economy and the indirect effects due to governments shutting down economic activities by decree. We find that the negative demand effects prevail in both dimensions and are far from trivial. For example, according to the point estimates of our baseline specification, a monthly increase equivalent to one standard deviation in COVID‐related deaths per capita and in the level of lockdown stringency would generate a reduction of nearly 6 per cent of imports from China (1.5 per cent stemming from the former, 4.2 per cent due to the latter). If we consider a change from zero to the sample mean for each of those variables, the joint effect would be an 11.3 per cent decrease in imports from China, while moving from zero to the highest levels in the sample would imply a joint effect of just over 30 per cent.

This is an incomplete picture, however, because one also needs to consider how a country's imports from China are affected by the consequences of the pandemic in the country's other trade partners. For example, for given domestic pandemic conditions, a country may decide to import more of a product from China if its main trading partners cannot supply it because of COVID‐related restrictions there. But just like in the domestic economy, the impact due to the pandemic's direct and indirect effects in the trading partners are a priori ambiguous. Empirically, we find that such a substitution does take place and the effect is sizeable. In fact, the same level of COVID‐related deaths at home and in the partner countries would induce an increase in imports from China, because the positive third‐country effect more than offsets the negative domestic effect. Accounting for the third‐country effects, the net impact on imports from China due to a one standard deviation increase, a change from zero to the sample mean and a change from zero to the sample maximum in the main variables would be a decrease in, respectively, 3.9, 9.8 and 10.9 per cent.

Unsurprisingly, we find that these average effects hide significant heterogeneity. Medical goods display a very different pattern. The effects are potentialised for durable consumption goods, but are moderated for those with a high ‘work‐from‐home’ share or a high contract intensity, for those exported under processing trade and for capital goods. The average effects for OECD countries are quite distinct from those for the average non‐OECD country, but our findings in the baseline regression are not affected much by fiscal policies related to the pandemic. There is also an important path‐dependence, in that COVID‐19 incidence of deaths and lockdowns in previous months tend to mitigate the negative effects of contemporaneous COVID‐19 incidence and lockdowns, suggesting that part of the reduction in trade may simply reflect a postponement of economic activities. This could help to explain why the aggregate drop in international trade in 2020 has been smaller than what many economists predicted at the onset of the pandemic.

The COVID‐19 pandemic remains in progress and its trade impacts after 2020may differ from its more immediate impacts, as workers, firms and governments learn how to deal with and adapt to it, and as vaccinations allow societies to return to their pre‐pandemic modes. How these effects vary over time is an interesting question that we do not address here. Given that our data are from China, we do not investigate either the possible interaction between COVID‐related effects in importing and exporting countries. These are promising avenues for future research on this topic.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We thank Joao Paulo Pessoa, an anonymous referee, Sangyoon Park, Longtian Zhang, and participants at the Economics Seminar at Kennesaw State University, 2021 Asia Impact Evaluation Conference at HKUST, 2021 International Conference on United States–China Trade Disputes and Rearchitecture in Globalization at Tsinghua University, the Eleventh IEFS China Annual Conference at University of International Business and Economics for comments and suggestions. Ornelas acknowledges financial support from the Brazilian Council of Science and Technology (CNPq). Shi acknowledges the financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71903188), the National Social Science Fund of China (Grant No. 21ZD076, 20BJL023), and Beijing municipal fund for building world‐class universities(disciplines) of Renmin University of China.

APPENDIX 1. 

FIGURE A1

The trade impact of the COVID‐19 pandemic (3)

Histogram of the dependent variable. Notes: This diagram shows a histogram of the dependent variable, defined as 100 times the log difference between countries’ imports from china in 2020 and that in 2019 at HS6 product level, monthly, i.e., Δimportipt=100log(import2020)iptlog(import2019)ipt

TABLE A1

Variable list

VariablesDefinitionSource
CovidDitDestination i's COVID deaths in month t divided by the total populationOxford COVID−19 Government Response Tracker
StringencyitDestination i's average lockdown stringency in month tOxford COVID−19 Government Response Tracker
CovidD_ROWiptFor product p and destination i, we first obtain the import value share in 2018 to construct the weight. Then, we calculate the weighted average of COVID deaths/population across economy i's importing countries of product p except China, Hong Kong SAR and Macao SAR. See equation (1) for the precise expressionOxford COVID−19 Government Response Tracker; BACI‐CEPII
Stringency_ROWiptFor product p and destination i, we first obtain the import value share in 2018 to construct the weight. Then, we calculate the weighted average of lockdown stringency across economy i's importing countries of product p except China, Hong Kong SAR and Macao SAR. See equation (1) for the precise expressionOxford COVID−19 Government Response Tracker; BACI‐CEPII
Medical GoodspAll products with HS codes corresponding to medical goodsWorld Health Organization & World Customs Organization (3.01 edition)
Durable and Non‐Durable GoodspGoods categorisation based on durabilityUN Broad Economic Category (BEC) classification (5th revision)
wfh_shpThe share of product p that could be produced by working from homeDingel and Neiman (2020) and Bonadio et al. (2021)
Contract IntensitypContract intensity of product pNunn (2007)
Processing TradepShare of processing trade for product p. Processing trade is defined as: the business activity of importing all or part of the raw materials, parts and components, packaging materials from abroad in bond (i.e. duty‐free), and re‐exporting the finished products after processing or assembly by firms within ChinaChina's Customs Data of Exports
Consumption, Intermediate, and Capital GoodspGoods categorisation based on their useUN Broad Economic Category (BEC) classification (5th revision)
OECD CountriesiOECD member countrieshttps://www.oecd.org/
Economic SupportitFor an economy i, government's economic support for COVID relief in month tOxford COVID−19 Government Response Tracker
Trade PoliciesiptFor an economy i, product p, the import/export liberalisation and restriction policies during COVID−19 pandemic in month tWTO
Extensive MarginitFor an economy i, the number of HS6 products it imports from China in month tChina's Customs Data of Exports
Exchange RateitFor an economy i, in month t the exchange rate is measured as the number of local currency units per USDCEIC

TABLE A2

Summary statistics

VariablesObsMeanSDMinMax
100*log(exp2020/exp2019)1,923,3350.600183.5−1522.81533.7
Stringency1,923,3350.5770.22201
CovidD1,923,3350.0340.07100.665
Stringency_ROW1,923,3350.5650.17301
CovidD_ROW1,923,3350.0510.06300.628
Wfh_sh1,854,1010.3750.110.1340.808
Contract Intensity1,885,7970.9140.0950.460.995
processing_sh1,792,8920.0650.20101
Economic Support1,904,8970.4890.30701
Stringency_prev1,923,3352.7972.01407.993
CovidD_prev1,923,3350.1100.20701.408

Note

The summary statistics of the first five variables are based on the sample used in the last regression of Table Table1.1. The summary statistics for wfh_sh, contract intensity and prc_sh are based on the samples used in Table Table3,3, respectively. The summary statistics for economic support variable is based on the sample used in regression (3) of Table Table5.5. The summary statistics for Stringency_prev and CovidD_prev are based on the sample used in the first regression of Table Table66 (same as the sample used in the last regression of Table Table11).

TABLE A3

Pairwise correlation among key COVID‐related variables

StringencyCovidDStringency_ROW
CovidD0.24771.0000
Stringency_ROW0.59760.21881.0000
CovidD_ROW0.26020.42590.4922

Note

This matrix is based on the sample used in the last regression of Table Table11.

TABLE A4

Economic significance of the estimates

VariableImpact of each variable on imports from China, in percentage
Coefficients1SD increase0 to sample mean0 to sample max.
Stringency−19.37−4.21−10.58−17.61
CovidD−20.86−1.47−0.71−12.95
CovidD_ROW28.591.821.4719.67
Total effect (in percentage)−3.86−9.81−10.9

Note

This matrix is based on the sample used in the last regression of Table Table11.

Notes

Liu, X., Ornelas, E., & Shi, H. (2022). The trade impact of the COVID‐19 pandemic. The World Economy, 00, 1–29. 10.1111/twec.13279 [PMC free article] [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]

Footnotes

1Source: https://hbs.unctad.org/total‐merchandise‐trade/.

2We also find that the effects are concentrated on the intensive margin. This pattern is similar to what has been found for the ‘great trade collapse’ that followed the financial crisis of 2008. For example, using Belgium firm‐level data, Behrens et al. (2013) find that nearly all of the fall in trade in that episode happened at the intensive margin. Bricongne et al. (2012) obtain similar results for French exporters. Bems et al. (2013) provide a review of the literature on the great trade collapse. This is not to say that the two shocks had similar global effects, however. As Le Moigne and Ossa (2021) point out, in aggregate, world trade has displayed much greater resilience in 2020 than during the trade collapse of 2008–2009.

3See Table TableA4A4 in https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/wts2020_e/wts2020_e.pdf.

4Friedt and Zhang (2020) use China's exports data until May 2020 at the province–country–product (HS2) level and find that China's exports are very sensitive to foreign countries’ new cases and domestic new cases. Che et al. (2020) use China's export data until May 2020 at the country–product (HS6) level and find that China's exports decline when foreign cases increase. Pei et al. (2021) use data up to April 2020 for China's exports at the city‐country level and find that Chinese cities under lockdown experience a 34 percentage‐point reduction in year‐over‐year export growth rate.

5Like us, Bas et al. (2022) use both COVID‐19 deaths and lockdown stringency throughout their analysis. They use monthly import data for the United States, Japan, Germany and France until July 2020, and conclude that the negative trade impact of the pandemic on these four countries stems mainly from inputs whose supply relies on China and that require a high degree of customization.

6We know of two exceptions. Berthou and Stumpner (2022) use trade data from 31 reporting countries with the rest of the world until November 2020. They concentrate on the influence of lockdown policies, and in a robustness specification construct a similar measure for third‐country stringency, although not for COVID‐19 incidence variables. Espitia et al. (2022) also consider a third‐country effect, but in a very different way, based on changes in third countries’ industrial output, and without using COVID‐19 variables.

7We do not isolate the role of global value chains (GVCs) in shaping the impact of the epidemic on trade, but several other authors have done precisely that. Bonadio et al. (2021) model the pandemic‐induced lockdown as a labour supply shock, studying quantitatively its trade and welfare impacts through input‐output linkages that transmit the shock across countries through GVCs. Based on a quantitative Ricardian model including input‐output features, Eppinger et al. (2021) analyse the influence of GVCs in mediating countries’ exposure to foreign shocks. Sforza and Steininger (2020) calibrate a Ricardian model with production networks with data from the first quarter of 2020, showing that the transmission of the COVID‐19shock through production networks magnifies the impact of local supply disruptions. There are also authors who investigate the role of GVCs in the COVID‐19shock with reduced‐form approaches (Hayakawa and Mukunoki, 2021; Kejzar and Velic, 2020).

8An additional reason for the reduction in import demand is precaution. Given the uncertainty created by the pandemic, consumers may want to postpone consumption and firms may decide to postpone production and investment. This precautionary effect adds to the negative effect on imports.

9Sources: https://covid.ourworldindata.org/data/owid‐covid‐data.xlsx and https://github.com/OxCGRT/covid‐policy‐tracker

10Source: https://github.com/OxCGRT/covid‐policy‐tracker/blob/master/documentation/codebook.md

11The lockdown policy indicators are updated on a bi‐weekly basis. The original stringency index is constructed based on nine sub‐indexes at daily frequency. The first eight relate to containment and closure: school closing, workplace closing, cancellation of public events, restrictions on gathering size, closure of public transport, stay‐at‐home requirements, restriction on internal movement and restrictions on international travel. The ninth relates to health systems, which is the public information campaign. For each subcategory, based on the judgement of the policy, a certain number of points is given, and then aggregated to generate the overall stringency index, which ranges from 0 to 100.

12Occasionally, a country may record a negative number for new COVID‐19 deaths to adjust for previous over‐reporting. Such negative values become very rare after we aggregate the data to a monthly frequency: they are present for only three country–month pairs among nearly two thousand pairs. We drop those three observations from our regressions.

13We exclude Hong Kong, SAR and Macau, SAR, because they are entrepots handling mainly the exports of mainland China.

14Source: http://www.wcoomd.org/‐/media/wco/public/es/pdf/topics/nomenclature/covid_19/hs‐classification‐reference_edition‐3_es.pdf?la=en.

15Concordance between ISIC Rev. 4 and ISIC Rev. 3 is from the WIOD SEA Source and Methods, https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/valuechain/wiod/wiod‐2016‐release, ‘WIOD Socio‐Economic Accounts 2016’, pp. 26–27. Concordance between HS 2007 and ISIC Rev. 3 are obtained from the WITS, https://wits.worldbank.org/product_concordance.html.

16Processing trade refers to the business activity of importing all or part of the raw materials, parts and components, packaging materials from abroad in bond (i.e. duty‐free), and re‐exporting the finished products after processing or assembly by firms within China. Besides processing trade and normal trade, there are more than a dozen other minor trade regimes, but they only account for about 13% of total exports in China during 2019–2020, with normal and processing trade accounting for 59% and 28%, respectively. We exclude these minor categories when calculating the share of processing trade.

17Source: https://unstats.un.org/unsd/trade/classifications/bec.asp.

18Codebooks: https://github.com/OxCGRT/covid‐policy‐tracker/blob/master/documentation/codebook.md#economic‐policies and https://github.com/OxCGRT/covid‐policy‐tracker/blob/master/documentation/index_methodology.md.

19Source: https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/covid19_e/trade_related_goods_measure_e.htm (as of March 26, 2021).

20Some countries are covered by our trade data, but not by the COVID‐related data (mostly constrained by the availability of the stringency index). Nevertheless, our sample coverage of importing countries is among the largest among similar studies.

21Observe that we allow the country–product effect to vary by year, but not by month of the year, which is the periodicity of our sample—otherwise, it would absorb all of the variation in the dependent variable.

22In the few specifications where we have separate country and product fixed effects, we cluster the standard errors at the HS6 product level.

23With 174 countries/regions and 4636 products at the HS6level in our baseline analysis, this amounts to 2*174*4636 =1,613,328 fixed effects. Using yoy measures, we still have one set of fixed effects, but they do not cause similar computational difficulties.

241exp19.371/100=17.6%, where −19.371 is the estimated coefficient of Stringency. We divide it by 100 because the dependent variable is in percentage terms.

251exp20.861×0.63/100=12%.

26We do not add the work‐from‐home variable by itself in the regressions because it is fully absorbed by the country–product fixed effect.

27We do not add the contract intensity variable by itself in the regressions because it is fully absorbed by the country–product fixed effect.

28See United Nations (2021).

29Here, we compare the coefficient of the CovidD previous cumulative value relative to the absolute value of the coefficient of its contemporaneous effect (i.e. 4.02/20.26=0.2) with the analogous ratio for Stringency (2.44/26.54=0.09).

30Alternatively, we add to our baseline regression two indicator variables for observations covered by a temporary import liberalization or import restriction policy. The result, available upon request, shows that the coefficient of the import liberalization dummy variable is positive, as expected, but is not statistically significant. The coefficient of the import restriction measure is negative and statistically significant, indicating that these measures, although relatively rare, did reduce countries’ imports. The other coefficients of the regression change very little.

31In contrast to us, Berthou and Stumpner (2022) find a negative and significant effect of Stringency on the extensive margin of trade, defined just as we define here. An important difference between the two analyses is that Berthou and Stumpner include only Stringency as the explanatory variable. If we drop from our regression CovidD, Stringency_ROW and CoividD_ROW, the coefficient on Stringency turns negative and significant also in our dataset.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

The data that supports the findings of this study are available in the supplementary material of this article.

REFERENCES

  • Anderson, J., & Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192. 10.1257/000282803321455214 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Antràs, P., Redding, S. J., & Hansberg, E. R. (2020). Globalization and pandemics. Covid Economics, 49, 1–84. [Google Scholar]
  • Baldwin, R. & Tomiura, E. (2020). Thinking ahead about the trade impact of covid‐19. In Baldwin R., Weder di Mauro B. (Eds.), Economics in the time of COVID‐19 (pp. 59‐71). CEPR Press. [Google Scholar]
  • Bas, M., Fernandes, A., & Paunov, C. (2022). How resilient was trade to COVID‐19? No 9975, Policy Research Working Paper Series. The World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  • Behrens, K., Corcos, G., & Mion, G. (2013). Trade crisis? What trade crisis?The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(2), 702–709. 10.1162/REST_a_00287 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Bems, R., Johnson, R. C., & Yi, K.‐M. (2010). Demand spillovers and the collapse of trade in the global recession. IMF Economic Review, 58(2), 295–326. 10.1057/imfer.2010.15 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Bems, R., Johnson, R. C., & Yi, K.‐M. (2013). The great trade collapse. Annual Review of Economics, 5(1), 375–400. 10.1146/annurev-economics-082912-110201 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Berthou, A., & Stumpner, S. (2022). Trade under lockdown. Banque de France Working Paper No. 867.
  • Bonadio, B., Huo, Z., Levchenko, A. A., & Pandalai‐Nayar, N. (2021). Global supply chains in the pandemic. Journal of International Economics, 133, 103534. 10.1016/j.jinteco.2021.103534 [PMC free article] [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Bricongne, J.‐C., Carluccio, J., Fontagné, L., Gaulier, G., & Stumpner, S. (2021). From macro to micro: Heterogeneous exporters in the pandemic. Mimeo. [Google Scholar]
  • Bricongne, J.‐C., Fontagné, L., Gaulier, G., Taglioni, D., & Vicard, V. (2012). Firms and the global crisis: French exports in the turmoil. Journal of International Economics, 87(1), 134–146. 10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.07.002 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Che, Y. I., Liu, W., Zhang, Y., & Zhao, L. (2020). China's exports during the global COVID‐19 pandemic. Frontiers of Economies in China, 15(4), 541–574. [Google Scholar]
  • Dingel, J. I., & Neiman, B. (2020). How many jobs can be done at home?Journal of Public Economics, 189, 104235. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Eaton, J., Kortum, S., Neiman, B., & Romalis, J. (2016). Trade and the global recession. American Economic Review, 106(11), 3401–3438. 10.1257/aer.20101557 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Eppinger, P., Felbermayr, G., Krebs, O., & Kukharskyy, B. (2021). Decoupling global value chains. Mimeo. 10.2139/ssrn.3848341 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Espitia, A., Mattoo, A., Rocha, N., Ruta, M., & Winkler, D. (2022). Pandemic trade: Covid‐19, remote work and global value chains. The World Economy, 45(2), 561–589. 10.1111/twec.13117 [PMC free article] [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Friedt, F. L., & Zhong, K. (2020). The triple effect of Covid‐19 on Chinese exports: First evidence of the export supply, import demand and GVC contagion effects. Covid Economics, 53, 72–109. [Google Scholar]
  • Hale, T., Angrist, N., Goldszmidt, R., Kira, B., Petherick, A., Phillips, T., Webster, S., Cameron‐Blake, E., Hallas, L., Majumdar, S., & Tatlow, H. (2021). A global panel database of pandemic policies (Oxford COVID‐19 Government Response Tracker). Nature Human Behaviour, 5, 529–538. 10.1038/s41562-021-01079-8 [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Hayakwa, K., & Mukunoki, H. (2021). Impacts of COVID‐19 on global value chains. The Developing Economies, 59(2), 154–177. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Kejzar, K. Z., Veli, & A. C. (2020). Covid‐19, trade collapse and GVC linkages: European experience. Covid Economics, 61, 219–240. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Le Moigne, M., & Ossa, R. (2021). Crumbling Economy, Booming Trade: The Surprising Resilience of World Trade in 2020. Working Paper 01‐21 Kühne Center Impact Series.
  • Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship‐specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600. 10.1162/qjec.122.2.569 [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Pei, J., de Vries, G., & Zhang, M. (2021). International trade and Covid‐19: City‐level evidence from China's lockdown policy. Journal of Regional Economics, Forthcoming, 1–26. 10.1111/jors.12559 [PMC free article] [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Sforza, A. & Steininger, M. (2020). Globalization in the Time of Covid‐19. CESifo working paper 8184.
  • Socrates, M. K. (2020). The effect of lockdown policies on international trade flows from developing countries: Event study evidence from Kenya. Working Paper. University of Nairobi. [Google Scholar]
  • United Nations(2021). World Economic Situation and Prospects: February 2021 Briefing, No. 146.

Articles from The World Economy are provided here courtesy of Wiley

The trade impact of the COVID‐19 pandemic (2024)
Top Articles
How I Learned to Accept an Apology From a Friend
Time Value of Money (TVM) Calculator
Katie Pavlich Bikini Photos
Gamevault Agent
Hocus Pocus Showtimes Near Harkins Theatres Yuma Palms 14
Free Atm For Emerald Card Near Me
Craigslist Mexico Cancun
Hendersonville (Tennessee) – Travel guide at Wikivoyage
Doby's Funeral Home Obituaries
Vardis Olive Garden (Georgioupolis, Kreta) ✈️ inkl. Flug buchen
Select Truck Greensboro
Things To Do In Atlanta Tomorrow Night
Non Sequitur
How To Cut Eelgrass Grounded
Pac Man Deviantart
Alexander Funeral Home Gallatin Obituaries
Craigslist In Flagstaff
Shasta County Most Wanted 2022
Energy Healing Conference Utah
Testberichte zu E-Bikes & Fahrrädern von PROPHETE.
Aaa Saugus Ma Appointment
Geometry Review Quiz 5 Answer Key
Walgreens Alma School And Dynamite
Bible Gateway passage: Revelation 3 - New Living Translation
Yisd Home Access Center
Home
Shadbase Get Out Of Jail
Gina Wilson Angle Addition Postulate
Celina Powell Lil Meech Video: A Controversial Encounter Shakes Social Media - Video Reddit Trend
Walmart Pharmacy Near Me Open
A Christmas Horse - Alison Senxation
Ou Football Brainiacs
Access a Shared Resource | Computing for Arts + Sciences
Pixel Combat Unblocked
Cvs Sport Physicals
Mercedes W204 Belt Diagram
Rogold Extension
'Conan Exiles' 3.0 Guide: How To Unlock Spells And Sorcery
Teenbeautyfitness
Weekly Math Review Q4 3
Facebook Marketplace Marrero La
Nobodyhome.tv Reddit
Topos De Bolos Engraçados
Gregory (Five Nights at Freddy's)
Grand Valley State University Library Hours
Holzer Athena Portal
Hampton In And Suites Near Me
Stoughton Commuter Rail Schedule
Bedbathandbeyond Flemington Nj
Free Carnival-themed Google Slides & PowerPoint templates
Otter Bustr
Selly Medaline
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Moshe Kshlerin

Last Updated:

Views: 6097

Rating: 4.7 / 5 (77 voted)

Reviews: 92% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Moshe Kshlerin

Birthday: 1994-01-25

Address: Suite 609 315 Lupita Unions, Ronnieburgh, MI 62697

Phone: +2424755286529

Job: District Education Designer

Hobby: Yoga, Gunsmithing, Singing, 3D printing, Nordic skating, Soapmaking, Juggling

Introduction: My name is Moshe Kshlerin, I am a gleaming, attractive, outstanding, pleasant, delightful, outstanding, famous person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.