Britannica Money (2024)

Influence of central banks

The chief feature that distinguishes central banks from commercial banks is their ability to issue irredeemable or “fiat” paper notes, which in most nations are the only available form of paper currency and the only form of money having unlimited legal-tender status. Besides being held by the general public, central bank notes also serve, together with central bank deposit credits, as the cash reserves of commercial banks. It is the central banks’ monopoly of paper currency and bank reserves that allows them to exercise control over the total supply of money (including commercial bank deposits) available in the economies over which their monopoly privileges extend. By altering national money stocks, central banks indirectly influence rates of spending and inflation and, to a far more limited extent, rates of employment and the production of goods and services. Central banks also can influence the fate of individual banks, and indeed the stability of the banking industry as a whole, by granting or refusing emergency assistance in their role as lender of last resort. Finally, central banks typically take part in the regulation of commercial banks. In this capacity they may enforce a variety of rules governing such things as cash reserve ratios, interest rates, investment portfolios, equity capital, and entry into the banking industry.

Monetary control

Central banks can control national money stocks in two ways: directly, by limiting their issues of paper currency, and indirectly, by altering available supplies of bank reserves and thereby influencing the value of the deposit credits that banks are capable of maintaining. Generally speaking, however, control is secured entirely though the market for bank reserves, with currency supplied to banks on demand in exchange for existing reserve credits.

Open-market operations

In most industrialized nations the supply of bank reserves is mainly regulated by means of central bank sales and purchases of government securities, foreign exchange, and other assets in secondary or open asset markets. When a central bank purchases assets in the open market, it pays for them with a check drawn upon itself. The seller then deposits the check with a commercial bank, which sends the check to the central bank for settlement in the form of a credit to the bank’s reserve account. Banking system reserves are thus increased by the value of the open-market purchase. Open-market asset sales have the opposite consequence, with the value of checks written by securities dealers being deducted from the reserve accounts of the dealers’ banks. The principal merit of open-market operations as an instrument of monetary control is that such operations allow central banks to exercise full control over outstanding stocks of basic money.

Minimum reserve requirements

Two other instruments of monetary control of considerable importance are changes in mandated bank reserve requirements (minimum legal ratios of bank cash reserves to deposits of various kinds) and changes in the discount rate (the interest rate a central bank charges on loans made to commercial banks and other financial intermediaries). Changes in reserve requirements work not by altering the total outstanding value of bank reserves but by altering the total value of deposits supported by available cash reserves.

The discount rate

The role of discount-rate changes is frequently misunderstood by the general public. Instead of purchasing assets on the open market, a central bank can purchase assets directly from a commercial bank. Traditionally such direct purchasing was known as “discounting,” because assets were acquired at a discount from their face or maturity value, with the discount rate embodying an implicit rate of interest. Today central bank support to commercial banks often takes the form of outright loans, even in systems (such as that of the United States) in which official central bank lending rates continue to be referred to as “discount” rates.

Confusion arises because it is often the case that, in setting their own discount rates, central banks are able to influence market lending rates. In practice, most central banks supply relatively little base money through their discount windows, often restricting their discount or lending operations mainly to troubled banks but even denying funds to some of those. Consequently, there may be no connection at all between the rates central banks charge commercial banks and other (including commercial-bank) lending rates. Some central banks have contributed to misunderstandings by using changes in their discount rates as a means of signaling their intention either to increase or to reduce the availability of bank reserves, with the actual easing or tightening of bank reserve market conditions being accomplished, more often than not, by means of open market operations.

Inflation targets

Although most central banks (at least those not bound by a fixed exchange-rate commitment) continue to pursue a variety of objectives, economists generally believe that their principal aim should be long-term price stability, meaning an annual rate of general price inflation that is within the range of 0 to 3 percent. While other popular monetary policy objectives, including the financing of government expenditures, combating unemployment, and “smoothing” or otherwise regulating interest rates, are not necessarily at loggerheads with this goal, failure to subordinate such objectives to that of price-level stability has often proved to be a recipe for high inflation.

Influence on market rates of interest

It is sometimes assumed that, by setting their own discount rates, central banks are able to influence, if not completely control, general market lending rates. In truth, most central banks supply relatively little base money in the form of direct loans or discounts to commercial banks. Central banks wield the greatest influence on rates that banks charge each other for short-term, especially overnight, funds. In some countries overnight interbank lending rates (such as the Federal Funds Rate in the United States, the London Interbank Offered Rate, or LIBOR, in England, and the Tokyo Interbank Offered Rate, or TIBOR, in Japan) function as important indirect guides to the central bank’s monetary policy. Yet even in this respect the ability of central banks to influence inflation-adjusted interest rates is very limited, especially in the long term.

“Last resort” lending

In its role as a lender of last resort, a central bank offers financial support to individual banking firms. Central banks perform this role to prevent such banks from failing prematurely and, more important, to prevent a general loss of confidence that could trigger widespread runs on a country’s banks.

Such a banking panic can involve large-scale withdrawals of currency from the banking system, which, by exhausting bank reserves, might cause the banking system to collapse, depriving firms of access to an essential source of funding while making it extremely difficult for the central bank to steer clear of a deflationary crisis. By standing ready to provide aid to troubled banks and thereby assuring depositors that at least some of the economy’s banking firms are in no danger of failing, central banks make the challenge of monetary control easier while maintaining the flow of bank credit.

Britannica Money (2024)
Top Articles
Embedded Finance: Everything You Need to Know
401(k) Loans: Should You Borrow Against Your Retirement?
Best Pizza Novato
417-990-0201
Brady Hughes Justified
Le Blanc Los Cabos - Los Cabos – Le Blanc Spa Resort Adults-Only All Inclusive
Apnetv.con
Blue Ridge Now Mugshots Hendersonville Nc
123Moviescloud
Builders Best Do It Center
The Superhuman Guide to Twitter Advanced Search: 23 Hidden Ways to Use Advanced Search for Marketing and Sales
Las 12 mejores subastas de carros en Los Ángeles, California - Gossip Vehiculos
3S Bivy Cover 2D Gen
Aspen Mobile Login Help
Wausau Obits Legacy
Danforth's Port Jefferson
Gentle Dental Northpointe
Epguides Strange New Worlds
CVS Near Me | Columbus, NE
Acts 16 Nkjv
Amazing deals for Abercrombie & Fitch Co. on Goodshop!
Rubber Ducks Akron Score
What Is The Lineup For Nascar Race Today
As families searched, a Texas medical school cut up their loved ones
Weather October 15
Chelsea Hardie Leaked
Calvin Coolidge: Life in Brief | Miller Center
Life Insurance Policies | New York Life
Craigslist Com Humboldt
Texas Baseball Officially Releases 2023 Schedule
Ukg Dimensions Urmc
Labyrinth enchantment | PoE Wiki
Rage Of Harrogath Bugged
Saybyebugs At Walmart
Final Jeopardy July 25 2023
T&Cs | Hollywood Bowl
Mid America Clinical Labs Appointments
About My Father Showtimes Near Amc Rockford 16
Sig Mlok Bayonet Mount
Pulitzer And Tony Winning Play About A Mathematical Genius Crossword
The power of the NFL, its data, and the shift to CTV
2017 Ford F550 Rear Axle Nut Torque Spec
Brown launches digital hub to expand community, career exploration for students, alumni
Iman Fashion Clearance
Fine Taladorian Cheese Platter
Shiftselect Carolinas
Skyward Login Wylie Isd
Nfl Espn Expert Picks 2023
Factorio Green Circuit Setup
Mast Greenhouse Windsor Mo
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Aracelis Kilback

Last Updated:

Views: 6087

Rating: 4.3 / 5 (44 voted)

Reviews: 83% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Aracelis Kilback

Birthday: 1994-11-22

Address: Apt. 895 30151 Green Plain, Lake Mariela, RI 98141

Phone: +5992291857476

Job: Legal Officer

Hobby: LARPing, role-playing games, Slacklining, Reading, Inline skating, Brazilian jiu-jitsu, Dance

Introduction: My name is Aracelis Kilback, I am a nice, gentle, agreeable, joyous, attractive, combative, gifted person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.